There's been a lot of debate recently about the quality of startups that go through multiple accelerators. This all kicked-off with Sam Altman's post Getting Into YCombinator which discouraged the practice. Responses included Dave McClure's Plays Well with Others and Calcanis's Incubator Hopping.
"We now have enough data to know that the track record of companies that go through multiple accelerators is much worse than companies that just do YC." - sama
Unfortunately other than the above statement (with undisclosed data) a lot of this debate was driven by personal opinions rather than any firm evidence. I've done a fair amount of work analyzing startup data both for fun and profit so I naturally wanted to get a better answer. I started by pulling together a couple of data sets on seed accelerators, one a personal one I've being building for a while and secondly Jed's excellent Seed-DB and started crunching them.
After filtering out the edge cases such as startups going through multiple cohorts of the same accelerator and startups that have gone through three or more accelerators I was left with a data set of 132 startups who have been through two accelerators (16 of which went through YC after another accelerator).
Out of those 132 there are two clear successes (>$100m valuation) - Sphero (which has raised around $100m in investment) and GrabCad (acquired for ~$100m). PagerDuty (around ~$40m raised) likely falls into this group as well. Roughly around 1-2% of all accelerator alumni end up at >$100m so from this initial analysis it doesn't appear going through multiple accelerators is a strong negative signal.
However the problem with this approach is that it doesn't adjust for cohort age (older companies naturally tend to be larger) or more importantly the quality of the accelerator. We'd expect the alumni of top-tier accelerators to be significantly better than those from an average accelerator in any case. Another issue with this approach is that we're talking about a tiny handful of companies so the numbers can be very easily skewed.
I got around these problems by creating a dataset that reasonably represents a group similar to our "double accelerator group". For each startup in our group I randomly picked another startup that was in the same cohort/accelerator to control for that effect and added it to the comparison group. I then generated several hundred comparison groups so I could measure the variance we would expect to get from random luck. I then segmented the groups by bands of how much money they had raised (using that as a proxy for progress) and measured the percentage of startups that fell into each band.
The green diamonds show how the double accelerator group performed compared to the boxplot showing startups going through their first accelerator. Not only is it not a negative signal, but overall companies that go through multiple accelerators tend to do meaningfully better than average for raising money <$20m and the same as average for raising above that (as these cohorts mature I wouldn't be surprised to see the >$20m raises also increase to above average).
While startups going through a second accelerator might do better in general the same might not apply to YC; after all YC is somewhat unique among accelerators. So I reran my analysis using only the 16 YC companies [1] comparing them against their own cohorts.
While there are some differences we again see that overall startups for whom YC is their second accelerator tend to be more likely to raise at each band then the average YC company.
In practice almost all of the returns for an accelerator come from a handful of unicorns and we can't know at this stage if any of these companies will become unicorns, but based on the early date there's no evidence that they won't come out of this group.
Footnotes
This should come with the proviso that YC almost certainly has better data than I do on their portfolio (I'm likely missing a number of YC companies which have been through other accelerators) but I'd encourage YC and any other accelerator looking at this to make sure they're analyzing their data in a reasonable way. I'm more than happy to share my modelling code with any accelerators which would find it useful.
[1] The 16 companies for reference were Bagaveev Corporation, Final, CribSpot, Labdoor, Chariot, Seva Coffee, Nomiku, Valor Water Analytics, Leada, Plate Joy, uBiome, FlightCar, Vayable, chute, MarketBrief and PagerDuty.
"Uber for X" has become commonplace model for startups but often such startups overly-focus on ease-of-delivery rather than what made Uber truly disruptive. Uber built a marketplace in a highly fragmented market that allowed them to change the entire dynamics of an industry. The taxi industry is only one of many industries that are ripe for disruption from online marketplaces.
Much of the money currently spent on mainstream advertising (Google, Facebook, traditional media, etc) is by vendors who would be better served by industry specific marketplaces; and it's only a matter of time before those marketplaces appear.
That naturally raises the question of what makes a market suitable for an online marketplace. To answer that question I’ve been working on a framework to help evaluate markets based on their intrinsic properties.
The framework is based upon analysing a large number of online marketplaces and identifying the key factors that differentiate the successful ones from the failures and understanding why those factors played the role they did. I’ve broken the framework into looking at the properties of the demand-side (i.e the customers/buyers), the supply-side (i.e the vendors/sellers) and the transaction:
Do customers make multiple transactions within a reasonable time-frame (i.e. several+ transactions a year) ?
Low vendor-loyalty
Do customers regularly switch between vendors ?
Large market
Is there customer spending of $10bn+ in the market ?
Expandable demand
Is there "untapped demand” that can be unleashed by a marketplace ?
Consumer Experience
Are there key problems in the consumer experience that can be solved ?
Fragmented supply-side
Is there a fragmented supply-side with small vendors controlling a large part of market ?
Low-conversion/High-conversion
Is the market low-conversion for individual vendor but high-conversion for the overall transaction ?
Supply-side servicing
Are there unique “add-on” services that a marketplace could deliver to their supply side because of their position ?
Expandable Supply
Would a marketplace reduce the barrier-to-entry into the market ?
On-Platform Transactions
Can the entire transaction be captured on-platform ?
Market open to a Marketplace
Are the market participants willing to move to an online marketplace ?
Willingness to pay
Are the market participants willing to pay for a marketplace ?
As part of my research into marketplaces I've been digging into the IPO prospectuses of three recent marketplace IPOs:
The three make for an interesting comparison study with Just-Eat and GrubHub being very similar businesses and Zoopla being a very different one, giving some insight into what a modern "unicorn" marketplace looks like and what early-stage marketplace startups should be aiming for in the long term.
(All currency amounts have been converted to USD; market cap as of 14th August; the ratio is marketcap/revenue rather than PE ratio).
While all three marketplaces have broadly similar revenues it's notable how much the valuations of GrubHub and Just-Eat have diverged post-IPO with GrubHub trading at significantly higher ratio (they have similar expenditure and growth figures).
It's hard to say if the pricing is "bubbly" but it shows a clear geographic influence in pricing. Although it's not obvious how much of the GrubHub premium is because of it's dominance in the US market (the largest single take-out market in the world) and how much of it is down to the fact it's listed on a US exchange.
Either way the implication is that US marketplaces can enter the unicorn club with lower revenue figures than non-US marketplaces.
On a broader level if we take 12-13x as a lower bound for these ratios then that implies a marketplace needs to reach annual revenues of around $80m to get into the unicorn club. Although it's worth noting that these ratios are for high-growth marketplaces which are the dominant players in their markets.
The Vendor Side
Although from the consumer-side takeaway and real-estate are very different businesses, the vendor side is much more comparable if we look at number of vendors, average revenue per vendor and revenue per lead:
(The revenue figures are slightly-off from the earlier revenue figures as they exclude revenues from other sources such as third-party advertising)
An insight worth pulling out is that even though the Just-Eat/GrubHub charge using a commission model (typically charging around 10% per transaction) and Zoopla charge on subscription model (vendors pay a monthly fee) that the revenue/vendor/lead figures work out roughly the same. It's not a case of unicorn marketplaces having to use one model or the other.
Given that the definition of a lead is very different for the takeaway marketplaces (an order being placed) and for real-estate (an expression of interest in seeing a property) the revenue-per-lead being similar might be coincidental; however there might also be some market dynamics at play that explain the similarity (i.e unicorn marketplaces that charge an order of magnitude less would require vastly more transactions making them much rarer).
The number of vendors and revenue/vendor that early stage marketplaces should be targeting becomes much more obvious if we graph the companies. As all the companies have similar revenues they fall roughly along what we can call the "unicorn line" - if a marketplace is serving a market in which it's hard to cross-above the line (i.e too few vendors; not enough value generated for vendors) then it's likely to be hard space to build a unicorn marketplace.
Interested in Marketplaces ? - follow me on twitter @imranghory
]]>Marketplace pricing strategies tend to fall into one of three categories:
Of these three models the commission approach has largely become the standard with flat-rate and subscription models being relegated to marketplaces where the actual transaction happens off-platform (housing, cars, recruitment, etc.) or where transactions aren't priced (data sharing, dating, etc.).
This convergence on commission pricing has meant it's possible to broadly compare marketplaces serving different industries and how the level of commission varies with the nature of the transactions. So to do this I pulled together an analysis looking at the commission rates for twenty-five different marketplaces across six categories:
To make the commissions as comparable as possible:
Looking at the data this way it's hard to ignore how high-commission digital product marketplaces are - the low-end of the category being equivalent to the high-end in every other category. It's not clear if it's a case of profit taking or if the digital marketplaces face unique costs (vetting product quality, marketing, etc.) but given that newer marketplaces such as Creative Market are operating at a much lower (although still high) commission the high-end digital marketplaces look distinctly vulnerable to disruption.
There's also a noticeable gap between the marketplaces for remote and local services with the later commanding a notable premium. While the obvious explanation would be local marketplaces requiring greater local presence and deeper supply side vetting, the holiday rental market faces similar challenges without the same level of markup. It'll be interesting to see if the rates get driven down as competition grows in the local services space.
One factor not taken into account here is transaction value and volume; in theory markets in which those are larger should result in higher revenue from smaller commission. However even once segmented by category it's not obvious that there is a correlation between those factors and commission levels. One reason may be that marketplace startups tend to either be "low-value high-volume" or "high-value low-volume" with the two factors essentially cancelling each other out (presumably "low-value low-volume" markets are hard to build significant companies in and "high-value high-volume" markets extremely rare).
If you have any comments or are working on a marketplace startup I'd love to hear from you. I can be reached via email <imranghory@gmail.com> or twitter at @imranghory.
This weekend was #FutureBookHack, a hackathon which brought together hackers that were digital leaders from top-tier publishers (Faber, Harper Collins, Pan Macmillan, Penguin Random House, and Simon and Schuster), as well as other industry experts including industry analysts (Nielsen), booksellers (Blackwells) and literary agents.
While The Bookseller has extensive coverage of the event itself, there hasn't been much coverage of the key themes that emerged not only from the formal presentations/workshops, but also from the more informal discussions that took place over the weekend.
Given such a unique collection of experts, there was a lot of industry insight which I've gathered together to share with a wider audience.
I've split it into - the more formal topics; (discoverability, audio books and children's books); the informal ones (Netflix for eBooks, Publishers vs Self-Publishing); and then rounded up some of the more insightful smaller points.
Given how "hot" this topic has been over the last year, it was almost an inevitable that this was bought up a number of times. Almost always via a participant raising it to one of the publishers rather than vice versa.
The overwhelming view from the publishers, was that the model didn't work for the dynamics of the book market. The fundamental argument being, that most readers aren't restricted to the number of books they read because of cost, but because of time.
While a music listener or movie watcher might significantly increase their consumption as the incremental price drops to zero, book readers are already close to their limit in how many books they can read.
For example, with music a single is only 2-3 minutes long, so with a subscription service the amount of genres to which a consumer listens increases significantly. An average book takes 10-20 hours of reading time and many consumers already purchase more books than they are able to read.
The fact that piracy hasn't occurred for eBooks in the way it has for movies and music, adds weight to the viewpoint that eBook consumption isn't price restricted.
As this is the case, it seems impossible for a pricing model to exist that would both make sense for publishers and readers. Readers can't be given more value for the same amount of money, and publishers can't justify the cannibalization of their sales market if subscriptions can't produce similar revenues. Publishers also lack secondary revenue streams (merchandising, concerts, etc.) that allow other industries to justify the low revenues from services like Spotify.
However, there might be exceptions for particular genres where reading patterns are different, and this has been demonstrated in a few markets. Comic books (via Comixology and Marvel Unlimited), and technical books (Safari) are both examples where readers are likely to increase consumption. They're also both markets where consumers often purchase physical editions of books they already have in electronic form, further reducing the impact of cannibalization.
There may also be other factors that play into market dynamics for specific genres beyond volume of readership. For example with academic books, a subscription model on the reader's side would be of value to students who would no longer have to carry around heavy books, and on the publisher's side it would solve the major problem of secondary market resales.
Some publishers are however looking at alternative ways of segmenting subscription markets. For example, book serialisation and models where consumers can subscribe to a particular author.
When self-publishing of eBooks first took off, there was significant concern in the industry that the self-publishing market could end up disrupting the publishing industry. This left many publishers in an existential crisis, questioning what they actually did, and how they added value.
As the eBook industry has matured the initial concerns have largely been allayed, with publishers finding that in general, self-published authors would prefer a traditional publisher if given the option.
Publishers now often sign up successful self-published authors, and source new books from services such as WattPad. Taking on such authors reduces the upfront risk of investing in a book, as the authors have already proven demand, so the overall impact has actually been positive for publishers.
Arising from these discussions was also the wider topic of what precisely publishers consider their “key value-add” and why authors still wanted to go with traditional publishers. Reputation, risk and expertise were the three key factors.
While publishers outsource many of the services that they provide to freelancers, they add value by managing those relationships. This both prevents exploitation (as authors aren’t expert buyers of these services), and removes direct commercial incentives from the equation (if the author was paying the editor directly it would impact the author-editor relationship).
The ability for consumers to discover new books was something that concerned all the publishers, who were keen to see technology formalizing traditional methods of discovery (social recommendation systems, aggregation of professional reviews ala Metacritic), as well as more innovative approaches.
The general feeling, was that current discovery approaches had significant weaknesses. Such as best sellers lists (both online and off) generally being rigged for editorial and commercial reasons, and recommendation engines (typically of the form of “people who bought x often bought y”) being skewed against new and more unusual books.
There was also interest in how improvements in book metadata could result in better discovery (i.e applying SEO techniques to optimize books appearing in the right searches), with most metadata currently being optimized through human expertise, rather than via data-driven approaches.
In part, it felt the concern over discoverability arose from the power that Amazon had over owning the key search, rankings, and book recommendation systems (both via Amazon.com and also via subsidaries such as GoodReads and Audible), and an interest in reducing the dependency on a single vendor.
Channels to market was the key topic among the publishers addressing audio books. While consumer demand is growing, there was visible frustration in the difficulty publishers faced in getting their product to customers - both in terms of discovery and delivery (large file sizes, clunky software).
Audio books form a unique set of challenges due to the way the market is fragmented at the moment. A literature student listening to an author reading his/her own work, gets a significantly different take on the work, as against a listener who opts for audio books while driving, or from a parent who uses a children's audio book as a substitute for a bedtime story.
At the moment, the majority of the digital audio book market is core genre adult fiction. This is partially due to the dominance of Audible, who's subscription model and marketing focus is on that group.
Audio book production is expensive to do properly as it requires studio time, a producer, and a voice actor. Due to this cost, base audio books are generally priced on the basis of length, although there is significant variation in how each is priced by the retailer.
So while audio rights to books are typically inexpensive, the high fixed production costs, the nascency of the market, and the fact that audio books sales don't seem to cannibalize the sale of non-audio versions, makes publishers keen to broaden the appeal of this medium.
The overwhelming interest from publishers, was to see new services that made it easy for consumers to access audio books, and many were actively looking into technologies such as streaming, and more consumer-friendly business models.
An unexpectedly hot area was children’s books, one of the few areas of publishing which is seeing a significant growth in print. It is also an area in which publishers are keen to see digital developments that will allow them to reuse their image assets for incremental revenue.
Due to the picture-heavy and interactive nature (pop-ups, pull-tabs, etc.) of these books, publishers are finding existing eBook formats and tools ineffective in bringing these books to digital platforms like the iPad.
There were also number of smaller insights raised that deserve a mention:
Following on from Y Combinator's Demo Day yesterday I ran an analysis on the companies that presented looking at how they made money. I looked at two factors:
The Data
(this data excludes companies which didn't present "on-the-record" at demo day)
The definitions I used for classifying startups:
The Analysis
The split between startups targeting businesses and consumers seems to be pretty even, in an article last month I covered how AngelPad strongly prefers b2b startups; this doesn't seem to be the case with YC.
Only a quarter of the startups that presented had no business model to date, although that rises to forty percent if you look purely at the consumer startups which suggests YC is still open to funding consumer startups that have the potential to be massmarket without a clear revenue stream.
Perhaps most striking was how popular the marketplace model is; historically YC have funded relatively few marketplace startups (presumably on the basis that the differentiator between marketplaces is down to traction and marketing rather than technology). However the huge success of AirBnB and other marketplace startups (Etsy, KickStarter, etc.) in recent years has possibly made them rethink their stance.
(This research wouldn't have been possible without the DemoDay coverage provided by both Dan Shapiro and Techcrunch so thanks to them both)
If you enjoyed this article why not follow me on twitter @imranghory
]]>Last night I attended a poker game sponsored by AngelPad (and kindly hosted by Pusher) who were looking to promote AngelPad as an accelerator to UK based startups. Thomas (founder of AngelPad) kicked off the evening by giving an introductory talk via Skype and holding a short Q&A session.
As there was a lot of useful information in that session I decided to do a write-up to help anyone thinking of applying who wasn't able to attend. Their deadline for their next season is this sunday and you can apply here.
I've add my own comments in [square brackets] to distinguish what Thomas said and my own take on what was said.
Keypoints
On applying:
On the startup:
On the team:
On what stage startups should apply:
On international applicants:
On British applicants specifically:
]]>
One complaint I hear from startup founders raising seed rounds is that it's often hard to know which VCs are open to doing early stage seed round investments and what size of investments they make.
Hence I've been doing some research and the following is a list of all significant VC funds who've made angel investments in London over the last year and a list of the companies they've invested in - in many cases the VCs in question have done a mix of seed and later rounds; the companies I've listed are specifically ones they've invested in at a seed level.
Where a fund has explicity stated the size of investments they make I've used those numbers, in other cases the numbers are estimates based upon the reported size of investments they've made in their previous portfolio companies.
Two VC funds in particular stand-out from the crowd in terms of the number and nature of the investments made: Passion Capital (who primarily focus on early stage investment) and Index - both of whom are definitely worth considering for any startups seeking to raise significant seed rounds.
The List
Passion Capital (typical seed investment size: £300k-£500k)
2011 Investments: Luluvise (female social network), WireWAX (video tagging), EyeEm (photo sharing), Adzuna (classified ad aggregator), Pusher (realtime web infrastructure), GoCardless (payment system)
Other notable investments: Mendeley (academic social network), smarkets (gambling), flattr (micropayments)
Accel (typical seed investment size $500k+)
2011 Investments: FantasyShopper (social shopping game), QRiously (real time sentiment analysis)
Amadeus (typical seed investment size: ~1m)
2011 Investments: TrialReach (clinical trial recruitment), oneDrum (Document collaboration)
Atomico (typical seed investment size: £300k-£550k)
2011 Investments: Ge.tt (file sharing), Silk (structured content), Siine (virtual keyboard), Fashiolista (fashion discovery), Hailo (taxi app)
Index (typical seed investment size: $300k-$2m)
2011 Investments: Reality Jockey (augmented music), EDITD (fashion trend analytics), Lightbox (photo app), Geckoboard (information dashboard), Lanyrd (conference discovery)
Other notable investments: SnapTalent (job ad network), netvibes (social media dashboard)
Octopus Ventures (typical seed investment size: £250k-£800k)
2011 Investments: CertiVox (secure content control)
Previous investments: TouchType (virtual keyboard), Secret Escapes (luxury travel), True Knowledge (natural language expert system) and Graze (postal snacks) (I've been told the last two were later than seed stage)
Profounders Capital (typical seed investment size: £500k+)
2011 Investments: Luluvise (female social network), Applifier (ad network), Lanyrd (conference discovery)
2011 Investments: EyeEm (photo sharing), Hailo (taxi app)
I've not included the following VC funds because I've been unable to identify any seed round investments they've made since the start of 2011: Balderton Capital, Dawn Capital and Eden Ventures, The Accelerator Group.
Apologies to anyone I've missed out or any mistakes in the above; feel free to contact me with corrections/additions at imranghory@gmail.com or @imranghory on twitter.
]]>Last weekend Seedcamp ran their inaugural seedhack, a weekend hackathon style event bring together industry specialists and developers to form new startups. Seedhack was pitched as a much more "serious" event compared to similar events such as Startup Weekend and Launch48, with the aim of having real startups emerge from it.
Startup Weekend and Launch48 are much more pushed towards having fun, learning and networking. That some real startups such as Zaarly have emerged out of them has been more in the way of a bonus for these events.
Seedhack bought in industry speakers, encouraged small team sizes and tackling of "real" problems, had paperwork to deal with ownership issues, and filtered the people attending (asking potential attendees if they were in a position to create a new startup, etc.). They also had two themes Healthcare and Big Data to help focus ideas on real problems for the weekend.
Unfortunately it doesn't seem to have worked, the products built were mostly similar to those found at any other event (apps for dating and coordinating meetups with your friends) and the follow-on rate (the number actually becoming startups) is likely to be similar.
What seedhack could have done better
The themes (healthcare and big data) were announced after most people had already signed up. It was clear many of the attendees had little or no interest in these themes.
There was also a clear lack of inspiration when it came down to ideas for healthcare startups because there were so few people (either on the developer side or the business side) who had worked in healthcare. It would have made much more sense to have the themes decided upfront and the event promoted it on that basis (as for example the Education themed Startup Weekends are doing). It would have produced much more "aligned" interest among the crowd and likely result in far more innovative ideas.
The theme speakers while very interesting, were probably at a bit too high level for the event. As someone asked the healthcare speakers in the Q&A "but what are the problems you want us to solve?". There were also several vague references to healthcare APIs but it would have worked much better if speakers had gone into details of the APIs. Also it would have been better if the theme speakers went before the more general technical speakers as it would have allowed the audience to be thinking about theme related ideas that could be tackled with the technologies being talked about.
The logistics of creating teams didn't work very well. Seedhack took the approach of having a forum for people to post their ideas and online voting. While the concept was sound, in practice this really didn't work with only a handful of people even voting on the forum. The flakey wifi in the room and lack of 3g signal probably made it difficult even for those who wanted to vote to do so. Team formation was done in breaks without any real co-ordination and it wasn't really clear what was going on.
Launch48 and Startup Weekend both use a similar format which works much better: Anyone who wants can standup in front of everyone and deliver their pitch, followed by a manual voting process, typically either a show of hand or by use of post-it notes. The top voted pitchers then move to separate parts of the room holding signs indicating what they pitched and attendees can go and find the teams they want to join.
In fairness L48 and SW have both run dozens of events and know from experience that online voting tends not to work (not just because of technical difficulties but offline voting also makes attendees more invested in the ideas they voted for - an important psychological aid to team building), but seedhack should draw on the expertise of these other events.
From speaking to a lot of the attendees business development and product management fundamentals was one area that many were lacking. While this was partially made up for by the mentors, it seemed many of the teams failed to ask fundamental questions such as "why is this better than the other solutions to the same problem?". While this doesn't really matter for weekend projects, if seedhack is seeking to inspire real startups out of it they should encourage participants to think about these issues.
While I don't want to seem overly harsh about seedhack especially as this was their first time running it, I do think their concept of a more serious version of L48/SW makes a lot of sense and has potential, so hopefully they'll iterate in true startup style and the next event will be closer to its mark !
]]>In Feb 2007 Paul Graham launched Hacker News with the following announcement:
Yesterday we launched Startup News, a new component of our site with a user-ranked list of startup-related links. We created this partly for our own use: we've now funded about a hundred people, so it doesn't work well anymore to send links around by email.
Another reason we created news.ycombinator is that there is currently nothing like it. Reddit used to have a good concentration of startup-related links, but that was because so many of Reddit's initial users were connected in some way to Y Combinator. Now that Reddit is so much more popular, the top links tend to be images, or videos, or political news.
...
But the most important goal of news.ycombinator was to create a place where founders and would-be founders can meet and talk.
This is the front page of Hacker News at the moment:
Now look at the Startup Reddit - it's much closer to what Hacker News used to be:
It's not that these links didn't apper on HN, a lot of them did, they were just drowned out quickly by other more mainstream stories.
To paraphrase PG:
Hacker News used to have a good concentration of startup-related links, but that was because so many of Hacker News's initial users were connected in some way to startups. Now that Hacker News is so much more popular, the top links tend to be general technology, or geek, or political news.
]]>(this article was initially written but not published before Michael Arrington's resignation, as a result of MG Siegler's post suggesting Michael was pushed I've decided to publish it anyway. It was written prior to the announcement of CrunchFund, but the issues discussed apply to it as well as his other investments)
The History
Earlier this year Michael Arrington (editor of TechCrunch) announced a change to his investment policy, previously (since 2009) he hadn't made any angel investments due to the conflict-of-interest with his editorial role, but as of the start of this year he began angel investing again:
When these investments are complete, in a few months, there’s a very good chance that I’ll be a direct or indirect investor in a lot of the new startups in Silicon Valley, and that will mean that there will be financial conflicts of interests in a lot of my stories. Either because I write about those companies, or write about a competitor, or don’t write about a competitor.
...
The easiest way for me to handle this is to be up front about all of these investments and disclose it in posts, which I’ve done and will continue to do.
The Problems
Unfortunately there are a number of fundamental problem with this:
Missing Disclaimers
In practice inserting disclaimers into coverage isn't happening. For example this post announcing Zaarly's launch which happened two months after Arrington invested in them (according to his Crunchbase profile), not only did it not disclose Arrington's investment, but it also listed the other seed investors while missing out Arrington's name. Furthermore of all the articles covering Zaarly's competitors such as TaskRabbit not a single one contains a disclaimer covering Arrington's investment in a competitor.
While I don't think this was done on purpose, I think it clearly shows that even in clear-cut cases it's hard to get disclosure right. But in complex cases it's probably close to impossible.
And unfortunately since Arrington became an a limited partner in SV Angels he's now likely to be an investor in all future Y-Combinator companies.
Techcrunch have recently been covering a large number of YC companies as they launch before demo day and not a single one of these posts has had a disclaimer about the conflict of interest. TC has regularly given favourable coverage to YC launches for a number of years, so again I don't think TC is giving YC favourable coverage as a result of that investment, but there's a huge difference between giving an incubator positive coverage purely because you like them and when you have an investment (indirectly in this case) in them.
Stealth Startups
There are likely to be cases where Arrington isn't legally able to disclose an investment. Many YC companies operate in stealth mode, meaning that investors can't disclose their existence. The obligation to keep the investment secret directly contradicts the principle of full disclosure.
Techcrunch Editorial
The nature of Techcrunch also creates difficulty. TC doesn't on the whole run op-ed articles (with a few notable exceptions) on startups, but rather focuses it's editorial judgement on choosing which startups to cover and give publicity to. Hence to follow the principles of full disclosure they would need to not only disclose investments in articles, but also make disclosures in cases where they decide not to write articles. Again this is something that doesn't happen in practice.
The Inherent Problem of Full Disclosure
Imagine the scenario: Techcrunch runs a negative story about a competitor to one of Arrington's companies, because of full disclosure Arrington inserts a disclaimer about his investment. The disclaimer would essentially be a free advert for the company he invested in running against an article slating it's competitor. The principle of full disclosure would mean that his companies would get favourable coverage by getting mentioned whenever their competitors got coverage.
The Result
These four problems mean that it would be very difficult for Arrington to stay on in his position as Editor of Techcrunch without violating journalistic ethics of full disclosure and the stated editorial policy of both Techcrunch and their parent company AOL.
]]>Even though I'd spent a long time following the startup scene and reading all the standard blogs and books before founding my first startup CoderStack (a job board for software developers) when it came to actually putting theory into practice I ran across a lot of gaps in my knowledge.
So I've decided to write a series of blog posts describing my experiences and sharing the advice that I wish someone had given me before I started.
I've tried to roughly break the blog posts into themes and the first (this one) is going to be about user acquisition.
User Acquisition in your Business Plan
If I look back at my own plans from before I started working on my startup I actually cringe a little at my user acquisition strategy, I made the same mistakes that I see many other startup founders making now. My strategy was made up of broad terms like "SEO" and "Advertising" without any serious attempt to model how much traffic each of these approaches would generate and what the cost of user acquisition would be.
Any form of user acquisition has a cost, it might be defined in terms of your time rather than money, but unless you sit down and create a model for analyzing the amount of traffic you can generate and what that will involve you have no idea if a particular form of user acquisition is worthwhile.
Any form of user acquisition can also be modelled whether it's viral growth, PR, SEO, etc. By sitting down and building a model in Excel it helps you evaluate the strategy and understand the hidden assumptions (for example for viral growth what percentage of your users will tell their friends about your product) you're basing your business on. If I'd done that to start with it would have saved me a huge amount of time down the line.
Once you launch and are actually implementing your strategy it's trivial to update your spreadsheet and replace your assumptions with the hard data and see how that impacts the end results. You might find that once the assumptions have to be modified to match reality that the strategy you're using no-longer works. And it's much much better to find that out up front rather than six months down the line when you're wondering why you haven't grown as fast as you expected.
SEO
SEO is hard, one prong of our growth strategy was getting decent rankings for focused keywords like "Python jobs". I went into this without really understanding SEO as well as I should. Even through I managed to get first page listing for many keywords (we were helped by getting links from sites like Techcrunch and Business Insider) getting into the top position for competitive keywords is much harder than I thought.
As a new startup you automatically get a penalty for not having an "aged" domain (older websites get higher ranking), but it's close to impossible to beat off sites which have hundreds of thousands of established links, even if those links aren't as focused.
I also didn't really analyse the numbers as I should have, the phrase "Python jobs" gets roughly 500 searches a month in the UK. The top ranked result for that search will probably only get 20% click-through (i.e a hundred visits). If you're 5th in the rankings, you'll probably get 15 visitors a month.
In many cases the SEO effort taken to improve rankings wasn't worth the resultant traffic.
If you plan to use SEO as strategy for your startup make sure you use Google Keyword tools to figure out how many searches are made on the keywords you're targeting and how many links, etc. you'll need to get in order to get a worthwhile ranking (I've found Seomoz and SEMRush can be good for this).
Advertising
I've talked about my experiences in advertising my startup extensively elsewhere, so I won't go into too much details but the key fact I discovered was that obtaining cheap traffic comes down to two things:
On pretty much any ad platform you can reduce your costs by optimizing your ads (in some cases by as much as 100x), so it's definitely worth investing time and money to learn which optimization techniques work well on the ad platforms you're using.
Our original business plan was based around buying long-tail technical keywords (e.g. "concurrenthashmap") on Google cheaply, this strategy didn't work as it was based on the underlying assumption that long tail keywords with no other advertisers would be cheap. It turns out that due to the changes Google have made to the Quality Scoring algorithm part of their Adwords platform it's very hard to buy cheap adverts on non-"commercial intent" keywords.
We were however lucky that we managed to figure out an alternative strategy (extermely targeted ads on social networks) that turned out to give us the cost effective advertising we were after.
Social Media
Having a social media strategy is often equated with having a presence on social media websites, but there are actually lots of different types of presence.
Usage of social media by companies generally falls into one of these three categories:
The first two help you keep in touch with existing users and perhaps generate repeat business, but don't really help you gain new users.
If you want to use social media as a user acquisition vector you really need to make sure you fall into the last category, and that means focusing on generating content that your users want to promote to their friends.
If you're a content based startup it's definitely worth driving your content through your Facebook and Twitter content streams, because it's content far more than anything else that gets shared through the social networks.
Direct Sales
Direct sales is one of the highest converting ways to get users. How effectively this scales obviously depends on how much each user is worth to you as it typically has a high cost per user acquired. Even if it's not a viable long term strategy for your business it can be good way to get your initial users.
I'm not a natural extrovert and I still cringe a little when making sales cold calls or sending sales emails, but it's much easier than you think and once you get started it gets easier. The first few cold sales are the hardest.
It also has the huge advantage that you're speaking on a one-to-one basis with many customers and getting invaluable feedback that can help you iterate on your product.
That's it from me on user acquisition, if you have any questions or have particular areas you'd like me to talk about in detail feel free to leave a comment. You can also follow me at @imranghory on twitter.
]]>Since the launch of Y Combinator six years ago there have been countless competitors spring up all around the world, the primary competitive differentiator being that of location. YC's stellar reputation both in terms of expertise and connections to VC firms has been unrivalled and due to it's international nature, accepting teams from all around the world, it has been difficult for other seed accelerators to compete in attracting the best early stage companies.
However the last year has seen a new type of competitor to YC spring up: Specialist seed accelerators which differentiate themselves from YC not on the basis of location but rather on the basis of focusing on early-stage companies that serve a particular sector.
By focusing on particular sectors, especially those with unique challenges or difficulties in getting to market, these accelerators are providing a real challenge for traditional seed accelerators like Y Combinator and Techstars.
Indeed in reference to Imagine K12 an education-focused seed accelerator focused Paul Graham the founder of Y Combinator has commented:
If you want to start a startup building things for schools, we encourage you to apply to Imagine K12, because frankly, we couldn't help you the way they can.
--Paul Graham
So who are these specialist seed accelerators ?
Education
Imagine K12 (San Francisco)
Startl (New York)
Gaming
Joystick Labs (Durham, North Carolina)
Social Innovation
Emerge Venture Lab (Oxford, United Kingdom)
Bethnal Green Ventures (London, United Kingdom)
Unreasonable Institute (Colarado)
Health Care
RockHealth (San Francisco)
Healthbox (Chicago)
Blueprint Health (New York)
It's clearly only going to be a matter of time before we see a slew of seed accelerators covering a wide range of sectors, some obvious sectors for accelerators to cover include:
Finance
The financial sector probably produces more custom built software than anyone else in the world and it also produces a lot of startup founders (Wikipedia, Amazon, Delicious and PayPal were all [co-]founded by ex-finance people). The regulatory frameworks and the nature of selling to large financial firms makes it especially likely that a specialist seed accelerator would be able to add a lot of value.
Marketplaces
All marketplaces (or more generally any two-sided market business) tend to face similar problems when it comes to bootstrapping and getting around the chicken-and-egg problem. A seed accelerator with expertise in all the different approaches in tackling this problem could help a lot of marketplace startups get over the initial bootstrapping hurdle.
Recruitment
Recruitment is a huge business with companies regularly spending upto 50% of an employee's first year salary in recruitment costs across the whole sourcing and selection process. There's a huge amount of opportunity for innovation, yet the barrier for getting adopted by traditionally conservative HR departments can be high. Having the right connections can make a huge difference in this sector
What other sectors do people think could benefit from specialist seed accelerators ?
]]>Whenever people talk about Facebook Ads (or even more generally "Can Facebook justify their $50bn valuation?") the conversation always tends to swing around to how poorly Facebook Ads perform.
That drives me crazy.
For the last four months Facebook Ads have been the single best source for paid traffic for my startup CoderStack - I pay less for better converting traffic.
This wasn't always the case. When I started out running Facebook adverts I saw low click-through rates (CTRs) and expensive costs per click (CPCs). Initially I was left with the same impression as everyone else: this doesn't work.
But part of me didn't quite believe that, so I set out to read everything I could on Facebook Ad optimizations, and when I discovered that wasn't much, I started putting time (and money) into running experiments. After about two months worth of experiments my ad performance had increased dramatically (literally a hundred-fold). I'd discovered that with a little work Facebook Ads can be hugely profitable.
I gave a talk on this topic at the London ProductCamp in February and more than a few of the audience were surprised at how much difference tweaking ad copy and targeting can make. I think what convinced people at the talk more than anything was the hard-data, when I said "I'm paying 1p/click" that's when the audience really started paying attention.
Unfortunately there's very very little hard data out there to convince people about how effective Facebook Ads can be, while I was willing to share my real-world performance data at an unconference I'm hesitant to publish it in public where my competitors could use it to compete against me.
Given the inherent commercial nature of advertising everyone else seems to have the same opinion on secrecy so very little real hard data gets published, and most of the data that gets published tends to be from ad campaigns that haven't done well (as the information doesn't give competitors any advantage).
To rectify that (and also to test my optimization skills) I decided to run an ad campaign from scratch for one of my side projects (my webcomic Theory of Geek) and publish the data.
In the interest of openness I should declare at this point that I got approval from Facebook prior to publishing this data, but that they didn't see this data beforehand, they just knew I was writing an article about Facebook Ads and wanted to publish ad campaign data.
Here's the screenshot of the Facebook Ads Campaign five days after I started it (I've blurred out some of the ad names but none of the other details have been changed):
Of course you could argue that as I'm advertising a webcomic I'm going to get a much higher CTR (and thus lower CPC) than if I was advertising something more "serious".
For my software developer job board to target software developers I am paying more than in this ad campaign, my best ad for CoderStack was 3x more expensive than my best ad for Theory of Geek. But despite that I'm still paying an order of magnitude less on Facebook than I'm paying on any other ad networks.
I'd also like to comment on how this entire ad campaign and all the optimizations were done with a budget of under £20. Even if you're running a bootstrapped startup, you'd have to be crazy not to at least experiment with buying Facebook Ads given the low cost of experimenting and the high potential upside.
I plan to write some more articles on Facebook Ads, covering the practical side of doing ad optimizations and also what I think Facebook should be doing in order to make their ad platform better for advertisers, if you'd be interested in reading them then follow me on twitter @imranghory where I'll post links to my articles as I write them.
UPDATE: Just to clarify a couple of points that people have asked about:
This is my fourth blog in the last three years, but it's the first I'm publishing directly under my own name. My last three blogs all achieved reasonable success each managing to build readerships in the tens of thousands, but in part that's why I've decided to start this one.
When I meet people at conference or meetups it's getting to the point where many people recognize one of my blogs, but not me, which feels ... odd. So I figured it's time to start blogging under my own name to remove the cognitive disonnance.
For those interested in my previous articles, here's some of the highlights by topic:
(this is a partial list; I'll come back and fill it out some more later)
Startups
Developer Recruitment
Politics